of  

or
Sign in to continue reading...

Risk Sharing: The Sole Basis of Islamic Finance

By Zubair Hasan
7 years ago
Risk Sharing: The Sole Basis of Islamic Finance

Ard, Arif, Islam, Islamic banking, Mal, Musharakah, Rub, Al-sa, Sales


Create FREE account or Login to add your comment
Comments (0)


Transcription

  1. RISK-SHARING : THE SOLE BASIS OF ISLAMIC FINANCE? TIME FOR A SERIOUS RETHINK Zubair Hasan* Abstract: There has been a misleading revival of an old precept in Islamic finance - ‘no risk, no gain’- in the wake of the global financial crisis that started with the 2007 sub-prime debacle in the US. The recent proponents of the precept argue that the basic reason for the recurrence of such crises is the interest based conventional system of financing because it subsists solely on transference of risks to counter parties. In contrast, Islam shuns interest and promotes, they say, only the sharing of risks, not their transfer. The distinction is used to make a case for replacing the conventional system with the Islamic; for that alone is thought as the way to ensuring the establishment of a just and stable crisis free economic system. Empirics contending that Islamic banks have faced the current crisis better than the conventional are cited as the supporting evidence. The present paper refutes this line of argumentation and questions its basis and contentions. Key words: Financial crisis; Risk-sharing; Risk-transfer; Islamic banks; ‘No risk, no gain’ precept. JEL Classification: G2; GD1; GD2 1. INTRODUCTION Islam prohibits giving or taking of interest in finance. Instead, it allows financing contracts broadly of two sorts. First is the financing on a participatory or profit and loss sharing basis. The contract may assume the form of mudharabah or musharakah. The second is what are called the deferment contracts wherein the obligation of the party to make payment or of the party to deliver the effects is postponed to an agreed future date. The generic form of this latter arrangement is known as murabaha or the cost plus system. The plus part is known as the ‘markup’ and derives its permission from an Islamic maxim that allows a time value for money in deferred price payments (Laldin 2013, 30-36). However, the early Islamic scholars swayed by some distinctive features of the participatory models regrettably put a rather restrictive interpretation on the maxim deriving from it a ‘no risk, no gain’ precept which, they thought, makes risk-sharing the exclusive principle of Islamic finance. The fact is that the maxim covers both sorts of contracts we have mentioned. The choice of one or the other category is discretionary; no preference whatsoever is indicated. Interestingly, the proponents of the ‘no risk, no gain’ precept accept this reality 1 without realizing that the * The author is Professor Emeritus from INCEIF, Malaysia. This paper is the revised and expanded version of presentations on the subject in his earlier writings. Notable are the additions to the Shari’ah aspect of argumentation and the supporting documentation. He is grateful to Mohammed Ashraf Iqbal a PhD student of his for going through the draft who helped remove typos and suggested also a few improvements. However, the usual disclaimer applies. 1 For example, see Chapra, (2014) and Osman and Mirakhor, (2014) for such acknowledgement. 1
  2. acceptance conflicts with the ‘sole principle’ tag they stick to risk-sharing; it becomes irrelevant, rather misleading. Instead, the proponents of the precept continue to parade their exclusivist approach without any let up. Their insistence on sharing of risk being the absolute and paradigmatic imperative of the Islamic financial system remains unrelenting. 2 It is instructive to recall how all this confusion started. The early Islamic scholars, eager to showing Islamic finance sans interest as superior to and distinct from the conventional, saw the departure point in its participatory modes based on the sharing of profit and loss in financing and hastened to deduce that risk-sharing was an Islamic imperative for claiming any share in profit. The view led to the coinage of the precept - no risk, no gain (Chapra 1986, 64, 166). The precept lay dormant in the literature, save some occasional mention until it was challenged in the literature (See for example Halim 1985 and Hasan 2005). However, the devastation that 20072008 financial turmoil inflicted on the global economy provided the proponents of Islamic finance with a fresh impetus to highlight the fallibility of the conventional system and push the divine one, as they understand it, to the fore as a replacement. The reason for the turmoil was, they argued, the interest base conventional finance which subsists on transferring risks to counter parties. In contrast, Islamic finance, they believed, promotes risksharing that ensures stability and equity in the growth process. The distinction led to the retrieval of the ‘no risk, no gain’ precept from the literature. The task of reloading it back on the pedestal is led, rather religiously, by Prof Abbas Mirakhor the First Chair Holder of Islamic Finance at the renowned INCEIF. Risk-sharing has been a major theme in most of his recent lectures including U-tube uploads, and publications he has co-authored with others. Some researches he supervises also focus on the same theme. He states his position as follows. Practitioners grounded in conventional finance, however, were interested in developing ways and means of finance that, while Shari’ah compliant, were familiar to and accepted by market players in conventional finance Scholars emphasized risk-sharing while practitioners focused on traditional methods of conventional finance based on risk transfer and risk shifting. In doing so, instruments of conventional finance were replicated, reverse engineered or retrofitted for Shari’ah compatibility, a somewhat regrettable process. (Mirakhor 2014, 107). The observations along with supportive statements in other writings of Professor Mirakhor on the topic may be put below as his basic convictions, without being unfair to him, I suppose.  The world’s financial system is inherently prone to instability and financial crises since it works solely through the transferring of risks, not through their sharing;3  Islamic finance which allows only sharing of risks, not their transfer can alone pull the world back from the brink of disaster. It is the replacement for the faulty crisisprone conventional system. 2 For deferment contracts are like interest-bearing debt contracts; sukuk are known as Islamic bonds. Indeed, the proponents of the principle themselves lament this being the position in Islamic finance. (See quotation from Mirakhor above in the text). Take note also of the very title of his forthcoming 2015 publication. 2
  3. The contentions coming from a senior academician and practitioner carry far-reaching implications for Islamic finance , its substance, character and direction. That the interest-based conventional system of finance is fragile and unstable is an established fact. That equity is better than debt as a source of finance is also not in dispute. The difficulty with the contentions of Professor Mirakhor essentially is with their ‘solely’ and ‘only’ aspects. These aspects need a litmus test to find whether his thesis has legs to stand on or tends to collapse under its own weight. This paper is a humble attempt in that direction. To that end, Section 2 briefly explores the relationship between risk and return to capital. Section 3 examines the proposition that Islam allows only the sharing of risk as the basis of financing. Section 4 extends the critical appraisal of the risk-sharing rule in its exclusivist frame. A number of empirical studies - Mirza et al (2015) being the latest in the series - claim that Islamic banks have faced the current turmoil better than the conventional. The proponents of the precept cite these empirics as the evidence in support of their claim to the relative superiority of Islamic finance to project it as a replacement for the conventional system. Section 5 comments on the efficacy of this evidence. Finally, Section 6 concludes the argument of the paper with a few additional observations. 2. RISK AND RETURN TO CAPITAL The adage ‘no risk, no gain’ presumes an unbreakable linkage between risk and return to capital. Is this presumption valid? Historically, the association of risk with return on capital emerged to justify the charging of interest on loans largely taken to meet basic survival needs or to perform social rituals (Rubin, 2011: 1313). The flow of money was mostly from the rich to the poor in society. The rates of interest were exploitative as borrowings usually did not create the means for their own repayment. In default, the transfer of tangible assets from the poor to the rich was a common occurrence. The emergence of grinding poverty and abhorrent distributional inequalities of wealth and incomes were the consequence. However, commercial lending grew rapidly with the passage of time and the bulk of the loans in Arabia were indeed for commercial purposes when Islam made its advent on the scene (Chapra, 1986, 64). But during the early decades of industrial expansion (1775-1825), people normally used their own capital in dominant industries, hiring labor and renting land and tools from others. The managerial function centered on the capitalist, and competition was moderate. Thus, Marshall in the first edition of his Principles of Economics (1890) could see an industry dotted with tiny owner-operated firms, rising and falling on their own while the industry continues to expand just as trees do in a forest which itself continues to grow. The analogy implied that the issue of profit appropriation was then of little consequence, with entrepreneurship and management forming a single functional entity. 3
  4. During this early era of industry , the income of the owner-manager naturally got linked up with capital In all the classical writings, the word ‘profit’ is found to be used in this sense (Ormerod, 2010). However, this association gave rise to much confusion in economic theory as interest also was attributed to the owners of capital. Early classical writers could not provide a basis to separate the two or justify their attribution to the same functionary, the capitalist (Knight, 1921: 23). The latter-day economists created the distinction between interest and profit by linking profit to risk (Hawley 1893), albeit they still saw an element of risk remaining associated with interest (Knight 1921). Importantly, however, Knight nullified all theories tying profit to risk. He did so with a simple argument which briefly runs as follows. Under perfect competition participants in production have, by assumption, complete information of the market and enjoy perfect mobility, economic profit must be zero; for normal profit that the firms get is treated as an element of cost. Dynamic change that cannot be foreseen, however, makes competition imperfect, and business ventures become risky―money invested could shrink. This fear of losing money divides society into two sorts of people. Most people prefer to have assured incomes rather than face uncertain fluctuations. Such assurance is available if they are willing to work for others. For, there are also people in society who are willing by temperament to derive their income by engaging in businesses wherein they expect to earn higher incomes as profits. Accordingly, risk divides society into the hired and un-hired factors of production, the latter being called the entrepreneurs. They are the risk takers and earn profit. Others like the workers seek to join the production process for secure fixed incomes. Thus came into being the residual claimant theory of profit (Hawley 1893). Knight (1921) regarded the possession of capital as a necessary condition for entrepreneurship; for, in his view, an empty-handed person could not guarantee contractual payments to the hired factors of production 3. And yet, Knight did not see any connection between profit and capital. He considered profit to be a reward for entrepreneurial services. The proposition must be discomforting for the ‘no risk, no gain’ proponents in Islamic finance. For, they do not regard the possession of capital as a pre-requisite for entrepreneurship. On the contrary, their mudarib is an empty handed worker. However, more damaging to the ‘no risk, no gain’ proposition is Knight’s treatment of risk in his work. He divides risk in two parts – measureable risks and un-measureable risks which he labels respectively as ‘risk proper’ and uncertainty, the division difficult though (NYU.edu 2014). Measurable risks can be insured at a cost; thus they pose no threat to business and being cost, 3 Possession of capital being a necessary condition for entrepreneurship in Knight raises the question: Is it really the mental attitude to risk taking or lack of means to face uncertainty that plays the dominant role in dividing people into the hired and un-hired production factors? To me the question looks more as belonging to income and wealth distribution than a matter of temperamental differences. 4
  5. cannot be a part of profit . The premium paid to the insurer is a charge against revenues like wages or rent the businesses pay. It is uncertainty the un-measurable risk that forces one to peep into the future but what he could see would depend purely on luck or chance. The bifurcation is of far reaching consequence for Islamic finance where gharar or uncertainty has to be avoided. The injunction implies reference only to uncertainty that can be measured i.e. to ‘risk proper’ as defined above. Unless one is able to refute the logic of the uncertainty bifurcation, risk-management discussions in modern finance – Islamic or conventional – must lose much in content and significance. For, measureable risk must be insured; the un-measurable ones or uncertainty we have no means to guard against. Beyond what can be insured at a cost, tawakal – welcoming what Allah may grant, profit or loss – is alone the best risk management tool for Islamic finance. Indeed, the present day risk management does not, as it cannot, measure total risk due to an un-measurable mix. Risk managers’ measure probable (insurable) loss and to avoid it incur an internal cost possibly higher than the insurance premium 4 Also, the risk-profit linkage we referred to above cannot be shown delivering justice, one of the top priorities of Islamic finance; for, no one-on-one correspondence can be established between risk and profit because of uncertainty affecting both. Furthermore, risk-profit linkage is but ex ante whereas the negotiated sharing applies to a division of ex post profit; no risk is involved. Islam allows sharing of profit (loss) of which risk sharing is a consequence, not the cause. The contribution of Knight contextual to Islamic finance is twofold. First, he provides a precise definition of what risk is and what it is not. In contrast, the proponents of basing Islamic finance solely on risk-sharing never clarified what they meant by risk or what distinction they make between risk-sharing and risk transfer? And, in what situation one of the two would hold well against the other? 5 Is sharing or transfer of risk to be within the capitalist class or other factors in production should also be participating in sharing? It is such sort of issues that we shall address in the following sections. Second, Knight took note of the rise to dominance of modern corporations that has characteristically changed the risk-profit equation in businesses; especially finance. Capital, organization and entrepreneurship have become distinctly separate entities with reference to their rewards. The bond between profit and risk-taking has much loosened. The appropriation of profit has long become non-functional, not governed by any theory, power is the arbiter. The proponents of risk-sharing do not seem to have imbibed the ramifications of this change and its impact on risk-reward equation. 4 There is a fundamental difference between the reward for taking a known risk and that for assuming a risk whose value itself is not known. Risk managers can measure only the mathematical probability of loss – the known risk but a known risk will not lead to any reward or special payment at all (Knight 1921, 1.11.38). 5 The fact that both conventional and Islamic banks use exactly the same formula to make provisions for loan impairment candidly suggest that either both share risk or both transfer it (Ibid Ashraf supra n.1). 5
  6. 3 . RISK-SHARING AND ISLAMIC FINANCE The claim ‘no risk, no gain’ is based on a rather restrictive interpretation of a leading Islamic maxim derived from a Prophetic tradition; it says: ‘Benefit goes with liability’ 6 The problem is with the interpretation of the word ‘liability’ in the expression as the bearing of risk in financial transactions 7. Islam allows profit and loss sharing contracts among financing modes but not to the exclusion of others considered equally valid. Risk bearing is a consequence - not the cause of such contracts. To put it straight, there is no such thing in Islam as a risk sharing contract which when entered into would result in the sharing of profit or loss. Liability in the maxim focuses on compensation, not on risk; for risk is not a tradable commodity in financing. Risktaking per se cannot contribute to production; ownership of useful things including capital does. Equity of a profit share can be better judged with reference to capital investment not with reference to risk. The contention finds support from another Islamic maxim, an inverse of that under discussion. It says: ‘Liability accompanies gain’. It derives authority from the Qur’anic verse 2:27 (Laldin 2013, 162). There has to be a compensation for receiving a gain. Thus, for a claim to profit, financier is liable to bear ex post loss, not the ex ante risk (Baqir as-Sadr 1984). Conventional finance is of course dominated by interest based transactions, but it is far from truth that it entails no risk-sharing. Equity holders share risk and equity dominates in long-term financing. Even when loans are advanced on interest banks do face the risk of default and of adverse movements in the prices of bonds and the collaterals. If there is a difference between equity and debt with reference to risk, it is of degree, not of kind. That conventional banks collapsed like card houses in the current turmoil is evidence enough to see that interest-based finance is not always or entirely risk-free (See Appedix). And, there is not, nor can there ever be, any worthwhile estimate of the risk transfers to serve as a policy guide. What capital faces in deferred payment Islamic contracts is not much different from the risks conventional bank face; mortgages providing cover in both cases. Islamic banks too transfer risk via hedging contracts. They also take collaterals to cover default risks. Bulk of transactions Shari’ah supervisors approve is debt based; participatory finance despite all effort and pleadings is still not popular. The valid distinction between Islamic and conventional banking is then not that one is entirely risk-sharing and the other is entirely risk-transferring; what matters in either 6 For a detailed discussion on the maxim see Professor Laldin (2013, 156-160) Presumably, putting the maxim as ‘benefit goes with liability (to compensate)’ – would be more explicable of its intent and import. It would also commensurate well with another Islamic maxim – legal permission negates liability. Candidly, the liability to bear loss in business cannot be abolished; it would go against the Islamic ban on interest. For details on the quoted maxim, see Professor Laldin (2013, 164-166). 7 6
  7. case is the proportion of the two in the mix 8 . It is a myth that interest-bank is entirely free of risk taking while Islamic banks are entirely free of risk transfers. The Islamic ban on interest need not imply that the ban automatically blocks risk transfer. It is a matter of interpretation. Indeed, there is an argument that in pure classical mudarabah where the worker-entrepreneur is empty-handed the financier transfers a part of his risk to the worker. The financier does not make any payment to him in case of loss. He reduces his own loss equal to the transfer earnings of the worker; in a way risk is in part passed on to him (El-Gamal 2014, 1). Furthermore, risk-sharing need not always be equitable. Indeed, it may rarely be so. Risk being an ex ante entity has no cardinal measure. The sharing ratio is a crude proxy for the division of profit. No one can demonstrate a one-on-one correspondence between the profit share of the parties and their respective risk exposures. Justice and fair play is the first requirement for calling something ‘Islamic’. The difficulty is that tons of juristic writings analyzing contract forms provide little help to determine whether or not there is injustice in an exchange contract. Arbitrariness is the rule 9. The present resurgence of risk-sharing is no more than the echo of the ‘no-risk-no-gain’ adage which is ingrained since long in the literature as the sole principle for organizing Islamic finance as noted earlier. The present author had a detailed discussion on the precept much earlier (Hasan, 2005, 16-18). Interestingly, the reiteration of the precept under review tends to rely essentially on evidence extracted from the mainstream sources rather than from the earlier Islamic finance literature. The mainstream writings in economics are growing fast and the literature is so vast that evidence can often be marshaled on either side in a debate, including risk-sharing, with impressive documentation10.9 Important, however, is to examine the logic behind theoretical formulations. At times the proponents of risk sharing switch over from a narrower argument to the cosmopolitan plane in their explorations without notice and without forging a link with their 8 It is interesting to note that some writers find Islamic finance inherently more risk-averse and thus holding the pace of economic development in Muslim countries; they produce evidence (Bacha 1995, Suzanna & Ola 2013) In contrast, those who argue that it is in principle based on risk-sharing have nothing to show as testimony. 9 Contextual to n.4, the profit which the owner of a commodity obtains through its sale is based not on the risk involved but on the basis of the commodity proprietorship, even if the price (and profit) increases due to his transferring it to the market for ready availability to the consumers for he continues to remain its owner (Baqir-asSadr 1984, 76). 10 The classification of the notes and references in one such study in the references confirms the generous borrowings from the mainstream sources; some even from the heterodox literature. The bibliography contains 325 entries. Only 75 of these are from Islamic writers. Of the 75 no less than 40 belong to the writers of the book itself. Thus, for the criticism of the mainstream positions too our scholarship essentially draws on the mainstream! 7
  8. narrower business oriented discussions (Askari et al 2012)1110. They unwittingly voice the concerns of market capitalism in restricting their focus to the risk of losing money and material while the risk that human beings face working in various sorts of production lines are ignored even as such risks could be and usually are more persistent and fatal to limbs and life compared to the loss of money in business. Men, women and children working in coal mines, glass blowing, cement factories, cotton ginning, on oil-platforms in open seas, on nuclear reactors or even controlling traffic at the crowded road crossings face hazards no amount of money can compensate. During cyclical ups and downs who suffer more – capital or workers - depends on the terms of contracts that govern their employment11. Acute is becoming the cases of victims of war, epidemics and natural calamities. Thus, if there is a case for risk (and profit) sharing among the providers of capital, there is one, million times stronger, for such sharing between labor and capital, especially from Islamic viewpoint (Hasan, 1975 and 1983). Finally, another distinction the proponents make relates to the fixity versus variation of payments with regard to interest and profit. It is argued that fixed return to capital is not allowed in Islam; even its use as a benchmark is questionable in some forums. However, this is only partially true. Islam does allow a time value to money as part of the price in deferred payment contracts based on murābaḥah (cost plus) - an agreed fixed margin financing mode). Deferred payment sales involving mark-ups are debt-based transactions (Hasan 2014, 14-15, 96,105). We are not aware of any juridical preference between contracts involving profit sharing on the one hand and those stipulating predetermined returns on the other if both meet the stipulated Sharīʿah requirements. 4. SOME MORE COMMENTS Knight (1921) was categorical that profit is not a return to capital; it is a reward for entrepreneurial services―primarily relating to direction and coordination of the business. But by the time he was writing the preface to the fourth edition of his Risk, Uncertainty and Profit in 1957, the corporate form of business organization had risen to dominance, the personality of the classical entrepreneur, as alluded to earlier, had disintegrated; decision making had become scattered throughout the managerial hierarchy of the firms12 and competition had become increasingly intense. What remained intact of Knight’s work was the distinction between risk and uncertainty and its implications for economic theory and practice. The distinction shows that risk taking cannot be planned to produce desired results.1311 It could be a personality trait but cannot be measured, and no economic value could be put on it. Thus, risk is a specific mental state that 11 10For a neat summary of the content of this work see Islahi (2013). Sticking scrupulously to the norms a book reviewer must observe, one finds Islahi more on the explanatory side; for the analytical and evaluative content of the review one has to read more between the lines. 1311 Knight’s uncertainty theory was reduced to a windfall profit/loss case of little significance as probability based instruments cannot predict or measure them (Hasan, 1975, 1983).111111 8
  9. instills in a person the fear of adverse consequences of an action ; for example, the fear of losing his capital as an investor. Two options are open to such a person; for example, the capital owner (i) He is free to desist from the action if he cannot overcome the fear of adversity, i.e. of losing money; no one would penalize him if he does; or, (ii) He must conquer his fear to act and accept whatever be the consequence. Risk-taking is purely discretionary for humans. For that reason Islam neither promises a reward to a risktaker nor refuses a reward unless risk is taken. Consider the following examples as evidence: 1. Risk free earnings: One can earn a profit in spot transactions without facing any risk. The postprice risk one takes is out of one’s own sweet will; it does not arise in the course of the spot sale and purchase transaction. Pecuniary gains arise, devoid of risk, in the form of wages or rent for contributing to the permitted productive effort. 2. Abolition of interest: One justification capitalism advances for charging interest is the element of risk involved in lending. Thus, the lender has a right to compensation in the form of interest No Islamic economist can deny that loans carry risk; why does then Islam ban interest? Simply for the reason that interest is not the result of any productive exertion undertaken by the lender to earn it. 3. Ban on gambling: Like interest, Islam prohibits gambling and earnings based on it, albeit gamblers take great risks and are even ruined at times. The reason again is that labor in gambling is unproductive of real goods. The ban on gambling also extends to the sharing of a pool of individual earnings. To illustrate, the Sharī ʿa h would not allow two doctors entering into partnership to take patients separately but pool their earnings to be shared in a pre-agreed ratio. This is to avoid the risk of anyone of the two not getting the just reward for his work due to the possibility of a plus or minus element brought in by the sharing of risk.(Baqir-as-Sadr 1984, 78). 4. Tools of production: The tools of production are not allowed to have a share in the profits of a venture even though they too are exposed to risk in the production process. But tool owners are not denied a return; they gain in the form of fixed returns (rentals). However, the Hanafiis do allow the tools as part of capital contribution provided their monetary value is agreed upon at the start of production .(Baqir-as-Sadr 1984). . 5. Some other earnings involving risk are disallowed: certain sources of income (gain) like magic, witchcraft, fortune-telling or jugglery are not allowed in Islam even if risk is involved because they do not contribute to socially useful production All these and the like are ways of illegitimately consuming one another’s wealth as no trade with mutual consent is involved (Qur’ān, 2:188; 4:129). Even though risk may be involved, gain/profit may not be legal. The permissible way of generating profit and its sharing is allowed in all cases where participants can be shown as contributing to socially useful production. Consequently Baqir-as-Sadr (1984: 76) laments as follows: Many have fallen into error influenced by capitalist thought which has a tendency to explain the point and its defense on the basis of risk. They say or have said that the profit 9
  10. allowed to the owner of the stock-in-trade (cash capital or commodity) in the muḍārabah contract is theoretically based on risk because even though the owner of the stock-in-trade does not do any work yet he bears the burden of the risk and exposes himself to loss over his cash or commodity to the agent trafficking with it; so it is the duty of the agent to make proportionate percentage of compensation against the ventured risk out of the profit agreed upon in the muḍārabah contract between them. But the fact has been made fully clear in the previous discussion that the profit which the owner of the cash or commodity obtains as a result of the agent’s trafficking of it is not based on the risk but receives its justification on the basis of proprietorship of the owner of the cash or commodity with which the agent traffics. If one wants to make risk sharing the fulcrum of Islamic finance to the exclusion of other permissible modes of financing, one must take an extended view of risk and show its applicability in various socioeconomic conditions as harmonizing with the Islamic norms of justice. An attempt to do so has to be comprehensive and complete to avoid raising insoluble problems. This would be a palpably horrendous task not worth the effort. We find the risk-reward equation grossly misleading. The profit which the owner of a commodity obtains through its sale is based not on the risk he takes but on the basis of the commodity proprietorship, even if the price increases due to his transfer of the commodity to the market for ready availability to the consumers, for he continues to remain its owner (al-Sadr, 1984: 75-76). 5. ISLAMIC BANKS AND THE CRISIS Let us have a look at the claim that Islamic banks have faced the crisis better than the conventional testifying to the inherent strength and resilience of the system. This strength follows it is argued from a close link between financial flows and productivity in the real sector of the economy. Nabil (2012) adds that the presence of diversification in Islamic banking sector across countries reduces the vulnerability of financial contagion. Ahmed (2010) confirms: “This intrinsic property of Islamic finance contributes towards insulating it from the potential risks resulting from excess leverage and speculative financial activities which are part of the root causes of the current financial crisis”. Many others including Abbas (2007) and Chapra (2014) have followed the line. The factors mentioned in these writings may have possibly kept Islamic banks less affected during the crisis but at the same time we cannot ignore certain other factors that may have softened the impact of crisis on them. Consider for example the following points. 1) Islamic banks are still too small to attract the contagion because of their tiny existence; the ratio of Islamic banks asset to the conventional was just 1:118 in 2011 even as it has been improving over the years.1412It has again climbed down to 1:112 in June 2014. 1412 The ratio is based on the volume of global financial assets being $213 trillion and Islamic financial assets $1.8 trillion for the year. (IMF Financial Report 2013). 10
  11. 2 ) 3) Islamic banks have not yet developed enough connectivity with the mainstream system for the transmission of the contagion. Even then, it is not true that Islamic banks have not at all been affected. It is on record that several banks plus Nakheel in the UAE landed in trouble and the state had to bail them out (Hasan 2010). Most comparisons employ econometric models where sample designs are dubious and the reliability of data as also their homogeneity over time and space carry serious question marks. In particular, the contagion within the banking system is a smaller matter than the overall effect of the turmoil on the totality of the economic phenomena. The injury to banks is not the result of financial markets’ chaos; it is just its reflection. The damage is the consequence of wide and wild lurching of the key variables savings, investment and wages causing national income shrinkages (Hasan 2004). Figure Figure 1: Islamic baking – Global Trends 4: Islamic Banking globalgrowth growth trends Source:Source: IFSB IFSB Survey Report Survey Report2013 2013(Modified (Modified)) Figure 1 is revealing on the point Notice that around 2007, the assets, financing and deposits of Islamic banks were in harmony. The movement towards 2008 saw an expansion in the excess of deposits over financing, a situation that reversed in 2009 but as part of an overall downward drift of all variables. A few individual banks in the Middle East did come to grief and in Kuwait banks in trouble were denied bailout. The evidence detracts much from the claim of Islamic banks coming out of the crisis unscathed (Hasan 2010). Thus, we find that it is unwittingly the same linkage between the financial and real sectors of the economy that is claimed as imparting relative stability to the Islamic system may in a way tend to work in the opposite direction. 6. CONCLUDING REMARKS This paper aimed at examining the logic and tenability of an old precept whose revival in Islamic finance is recently being sought vociferously. The precept is claimed to mean that Islam permits no gain unless risk is involved in its earning. It is further argued that risk-sharing alone is commensurate with Islamic norms of financing. The supporters of the view blame the increasing 11
  12. recurrence of financial crises on interest-based finance because it promotes , they say, only the shifting of risks in financing, not their sharing. This critique has highlighted the unacceptability of this line of argument on both the juridical and feasibility fronts. The paper explains that the three Islamic maxims – benefit goes with liability, liability accompanies gain and deferment constitutes a part in price – read together lead us to only one conclusion that the right to receive any permissible benefit carries in Islam a counter liability to compensate the benefactor unless there is a legal waiver. The law remains neutral towards the exogenous consequences of meeting such liability, be it the risk to money, limb or life. One must also note that interest-based financing is not altogether devoid of risk nor all transactions in Islamic finance need be based on risk-sharing in the same way as it is shared in the case of equity. It is interesting that the Kuala Lumpur Declaration of October 1, 2012 on risksharing as an alternative to interest-based finance by-passed the proposal 13 to say only this much: “Governments should endeavor to move away from interest-based systems towards enhancing risk sharing systems by leveling the playing field between equity and debt.” 14 The paper establishes that the ‘no risk, no gain’ precept cannot be defended as an exclusive principle of Islamic finance. Risk is not a tradable commodity; nor is it an act in itself contributing to the value of output. Many transactions involving risk are not allowed while many transactions not involving it are. The principle of sharing of profit and loss is valid, but its basis is not the existence or absence of risk. In evaluating a situation and its causes, the moral and ethical dimension invariably escapes our attention. Principles of economics are essentially principles of economic policy, and no policy is worth more than what it is in execution. An Islamic Development Bank (IDB) publication aptly says: At its heart, Islamic finance is a moral system of finance. It emphasizes the balance between for-profit activities, or the market, and not-for-profit activities, including social and philanthropic activities. No economy can enjoy sustainable prosperity without the two domains in healthy equilibrium. Just as a bird cannot fly smoothly without the two wings properly functioning in tandem, an economy cannot “fly” without the two domains properly operating and serving the common good of the society (Al-Suwailem’ , 2014). 13 It must be noted that it was the paper of Professor Abass pleading for risk-sharing as the sole basis of Islamic finance that formed the basis of discussion at that high powered seminar. And his views can be attributed to INCEIF where he works. 14 The KL Declaration is provided as an Appendix for a ready reference to the readers. The content is too brief and deficient in explanation. Some of the statements it contains are open-ended. To us, it accords no status to profit sharing as an exclusive principle of Islamic finance. 12
  13. Most of the writings in the area of Islamic economics and finance are oblivious to the fact that the spiritual /moral wing of the bird today is utterly non-functional, if not broken; for, it is the moral stimuli ingrained in human nature that inspires people to undertake ‘not-for-profit' activities to help others. They present their postulates on the tacit assumption that people are reasonably committed to moral and ethical norms, which is unfortunately not the case. When confronted with the choice of reaping economic benefits or obeying religious imperatives, worldly concerns tend to outweigh the Hereafter consideration. The proponents of making risk sharing the sole basis of Islamic finance should re-evaluate the Sharīʿah basis of their argument. They should as well evaluate the feasibility of their suggestions. It may be noted that risk taking is not the same thing as risk sharing or risk transfer; it is fuzzy as to what variables could capture each of these expressions for the model remaining free of internal inconstancies. In any case, such models cannot deal with the totality of risk that banks face; they only deal with its measurable truncated part. And, where variables are socked with morality norms, the use of non-parametric methods seems to have an edge over the probabilitybased explorations now so fashionable in Islamic finance research. Finally, this paper is neither opposed to sharing of risk nor does it seek to mitigate the need for risk management. It is just an attempt to arrest the perilous tilt the emphasis on a non-existent ‘solely and only’ character of Islamic finance in the current literature has the proclivity of providing to its future growth. Appendix KUALA LUMPUR DECLARATION (Emphasis added) The Second Strategic Roundtable Discussion, jointly organized by the International Shari'ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance (ISRA), the Islamic Research and Training Institute (IRTI) and Durham University, met on 20th September 2012 in Lanai Kijang, Kuala Lumpur. After lengthy deliberations on the issue of risk sharing, the participants acknowledged that the financial crisis which started in 2008 highlighted the fact that the most salient feature of the dominant conventional financial system is the transfer of risks away from financial institutions onto customers, governments and the public at large. Islamic finance is in a unique position to offer an alternative to the present interest-based debt financing regime that has brought the whole world to the edge of collapse. Bearing this in mind, the second annual ISRA-IRTI-Durham Strategic Roundtable Discussion (2012) agreed on the following: • The Shari’ah emphasizes risk sharing as a salient characteristic of Islamic financial transactions. This is not only exemplified in equity-based contracts, like musharakah and mudarabah, but even in exchange contracts, such as sales and leasing, whereby risk is shared by virtue of possession. 13
  14. • Risk transfer and risk shifting in exchange contracts violate the Shari’ah principle that liability is inseparable from the right to profit. • Sales must be genuine transactions in open markets. • Although the Shari’ah recognizes the permissibility of debt, it is acknowledged that excessive debt has detrimental effects on society. The recommendations of the Roundtable Discussion are as follows: 1. Governments should endeavour to move away from interest-based systems towards enhancing risk-sharing systems by levelling the playing field between equity and debt. 2. Accordingly, governments should increase their use of fiscal and monetary policies based on risk sharing. 3. Governments could issue macro market instruments that would provide their treasuries with a significant source of non-interest-rate-based financing while promoting risk sharing, provided that these securities meet three conditions: (i) they are of low denomination; (ii) are sold on the retail market; and (iii) come with strong governance oversight. 4. There is a need to broaden the organizational structures beyond traditional banking models to formats such as venture capital and waqfs to fulfil the social goals and risk-sharing features of Islamic finance. ----------------------------------------------------------- .References Ahmad, M. M & Pandey, D. (2010): Are Islamic banks better immunized than conventional banks in the current financial crisis, 10th Global Conference on Business and Economics, Rome, Italy. Al-Suwailem, S. (2014): Essence of Islamic Finance. Jeddah: Islamic Development Bank (IDB). Askari, H, Iqbal, Z., Krichene, N. & Mirakhor, A. (2012: Risk Sharing in Finance: The Islamic Finance Alternative. Singapore: Wiley. Askari, H. & Mirakhor, A. (2014).Risk Sharing, Public Policy and the Contribution of Islamic Finance. PSL Quarterly Review, 67(271), 345-379. Bacha, Obiyathulla Ismath (1995): Conventional Versus Mudarabah Financing: An Agency Cost Perspective, IIUM Journal of Economics and Management, vol. 4(2), pages 33-50, Baqir-as-Sadr (1984). Iqtisaduna [Our Economy; Translated from Arabic]. Vol. 2.Tehran, Iran: World Organization for Islamic Services (WOIS). Chapra, M. U. (1986).Towards a Just Monetary System, Leicester, UK: Islamic Foundation. 14
  15. Chapra , M.U. (2014).Morality and Justice in Islamic Economics and Finance, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. El-Gamal, M. (2014).Exploitative Profit Sharing: On the Incoherence of All Contract-based Approaches to “Islamic Finance”. Retrieved from http://elgamal.blogspot.com/atom.xml. Gulzar, Rosana and Masih M. (2015): Islamic banking: 40 years later, still interest-based? Evidence from Malaysia, MPRA Paper No. 65840. Halim, A. (2001).The Deferred Contracts of Exchange: Al-Qur’an in Contrast with the Islamic Economist’s Theory on Banking and Finance. Malaysia: IKIM. Hasan, Z. (1975). Theory of Profit, New Delhi: Vikas Publishing House Pvt. Ltd. Hasan, Z. (1983). Theory of Profit: The Islamic Viewpoint. Journal of Research in Islamic Economics, KAAU, 1(1), 1-17. Hasan, Zubair (2004): Measuring Efficiency of Islamic Banks: Criteria, Methods, and Social priorities, Review of Islamic Economic, UK Vol. 8 No.2, pp. 1-30 Hasan, Z. (2005). Islamic Banking at the Crossroads: Theory versus Practice. In Iqbal, M. & Wilson, R. (Eds.).Islamic Perspectives on Wealth Creation(pp. 11-25).UK: Edinburgh University Press. Hasan, Z. (2010):Dubai financial crisis: causes, bailout and after, Journal of Islamic Banking & Finance, Vol. 27, No. 3, July- September, PP. 47-55 Hasan, Z. (2014). Islamic Banking & Finance: An Integrative Approach, Oxford University Press UK. Hawley, F B. (1893): The Risk Theory of Profit, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 7. Islahi, A. A (2013): Book Review - Risk-sharing in Finance: The Islamic Finance Alternative John Wiley and Sons (Asia), Pte. Ltd. Singapore, 2012 ISRA, IRTI & Durham University (September 2012), Kuala Lumpur Declaration Knight, F. H. (1921).Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. Laldin, M. Akram (2013): Islamic legal maxims & their application in Islamic finance, ISRA. Malik, M. S., Malik, A. & Mustafa, W. (2011). Controversies That Make Islamic Banking Controversial: An Analysis of Issues and Challenges. American Journal of Social and Management Sciences, 2(1), 41-46. Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan Co. 15
  16. Mirakhor , A. (2015): Social Capital and Risk Sharing; An Islamic Finance Paradigm. Palgrave Macmillan (Forthcoming). Mirakhor, A. (2014).Foundations of Risk-Sharing Finance: An Islamic View. In Lewis, K. Ariff, M .& Mohamad, S. (Eds.).Risk and Regulation of Islamic Banking.UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Mirakhor, A (July 8, 2015): Issues in Islamic Finance: Risk Sharing – an Economic Revolution, INCEIF: The Global University Of Islamic Finance on U-Tube Accessed on October 16, 2015 Nabi, M. S. (2013). Access to Finance and Investment: Does Profit Sharing Dominate Debt. IRTI Working Paper 1434‐02. NYU.edu (2014).Chapter 4: How do we measure risk? Retrieved from http://people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/valrisk/ch4.pdf Ormerod, P. (2010). Risk, Recessions and the Resilience of the Capitalist Economies/ Risk Management, 12, 83–99. Osman, A. and Mirakhor, A. (2014): Risk Sharing and Public Finance. Journal of Islamic Business and Management, 4(1), 56-72. Reich, Robert (2015): In the New Economy, Workers Take on All the Risk, Posted on August 25, 2015 by Yves Smith, Available on the following URL, Accessed on September 20, 2015. https://www.google.co.in/webhp?sourceid=chrome-instant&ion=1&espv=2&ie=UTF8#q=Robert+Reich%3A+In+the+New+Economy%2C+Workers+Take+on+All+the+Risk Rubin, J. (2011). Institutions, the Rise of Commerce and the Persistence of Laws: Interest Restrictions in Islam and Christianity. Economic Journal, 121, 1310-1339. Suzanna El Massah, Ola Al-Sayed (2013): Risk aversion and Islamic finance: an experimental approach, International Journal of Information Technology and Business Management Vol.16 No.1 PP.49-77 – ---- ----- 16